By Michael Spence*
MILAN – Markets and capitalist incentives
have great strengths in promoting economic efficiency, growth, and innovation.
And, as Ben Friedman of Harvard University argued persuasively in his 2006 book The Moral Consequences of Growth, economic growth
is good for open and democratic societies. But markets and capitalist
incentives have clear weaknesses in ensuring stability, equity, and
sustainability, which can adversely affect political and social cohesion.
Obviously, abandoning market-capitalist systems, and implicitly growth, is
not really an option. Collectively, we have little choice but to try to adapt
the system to changing technological and global conditions in order to achieve
stability, equity (in terms of opportunity and outcomes alike), and
sustainability. Of these three imperatives, sustainability may be the most
complex and challenging.
For many people, sustainability is associated with finite natural resources
and the environment. The global economy will probably triple in size in the
next quarter-century, largely owing to growth in developing countries as they
catch up to developed-country incomes and adopt similar consumption patterns.
Thus, there is a well-founded fear that the planet’s natural resources (broadly
defined) and recuperative capacities will not withstand the pressure.
To some, this logic leads to the conclusion that growth is the problem, and
that less growth is the solution. But, in developing countries, where only
sustained growth can lift people out of poverty, limiting it cannot be the
answer. The alternative is to change the growth model in order to lighten the
impact of higher levels of economic activity on natural resources and the
environment.
But there is no existing alternative to which we can all switch. Changing
the growth model means inventing a new one over time, step-by-step, from
complementary parts. The two key ingredients seem to be education and values.
Everyone, not just policymakers, needs to understand the consequences of our
individual and collective choices. We need to be aware for example, that
population growth and rising consumption levels have intergenerational
consequences, and that how we conduct ourselves will affect the lifestyles and
opportunities of our children and grandchildren.
Thus far, the quality of our choices has been unimpressive, reflecting
little sensitivity to sustainability and the impact of our choices on future
generations. As a result, many developed countries have built up dangerously
large public debts and even larger non-debt liabilities, owing to unsustainable
growth patterns.
Most of us, I believe, do not knowingly make choices that adversely affect
future generations. So perhaps incomplete knowledge of the consequences of our
choices is responsible. Moreover, an unfunded liability path, once taken, is
hard to leave, because at the point of departure, some generation is paying for
past commitments and at least beginning to fund future ones. That seems unfair,
because it is.
Most people might agree that living beyond our means in the aggregate, via
unfunded social services and insurance, or disproportionate use of resources,
imposes a burden on our offspring. But we might still fail to reach agreement
on who should pay for funding these programs, or for reducing our consumption
of resources. Too often, it is easier to deal with the distributional problem
by shifting the burden to those who are not present, and who are insufficiently
represented by those who are.
Education and values are the foundation of sound individual and,
ultimately, collective choices. Without them, the incentives and policies that
economists rightly argue are needed to increase energy efficiency, limit carbon
emissions, economize on water usage, and much more will lack support and fail
in the democratic decision-making process.
If sustainability is to triumph, it must be predominantly a bottom-up
process. Environmentalists are right to focus on education and individual
choices, even when their policy proposals are not always on target. Education
and values will drive local innovation, alter lifestyles, and shift social
norms. They will also affect business behavior via choices by customers and
employees, including business leaders. Thus, they are essential components of
the formulas needed to pursue sustainable patterns of growth.
But, while education and values are necessary, they clearly are not
sufficient. Complementary national policies and international agreements will
require careful scientific and economic analysis and thoughtful choices. The
need for burden-sharing, particularly between advanced and developing
countries, will not magically disappear. Climate-change risks, though serious,
should not be mistaken for the entire sustainability agenda.
There are clear steps that can be taken. Appropriate regulation and
sufficiently long time horizons can make structures of all kinds much more
energy-efficient, without imposing burdensome costs. In a similar way,
transportation can become less energy-intensive without restricting mobility.
Some of these shifts might be subject to international coordination, in order
to avoid adverse competitive consequences, whether real or perceived.
But too much coordination can be a bad thing. That is why climate-change
negotiations are shifting from the misguided objective of seeking risky 50-year
commitments to binding carbon-emissions targets to focusing on parallel,
step-by-step processes, including higher energy efficiency, better urban
planning, improved transportation systems, and on learning as we go. Likewise,
businesses and industries that are heavy water users will simply develop new
technologies and thrive in the face of scarcity.
Progress has been helped by growing awareness in populous Asia – and in
developing countries generally – that sustainability is the key to achieving
their longer-term growth objectives. This perspective perhaps comes more
naturally in an environment of rapid growth, because their growth models
require continual review and adaptation to be sustainable.
Over time, values shift as knowledge is acquired and disseminated. Policies
aimed at sustainability are likely to follow. What is unknown is whether we
will reach that point fast enough to avoid major disruptions, or even potential
conflict.
Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in
economics, is Professor of Economics at New York University’s Stern School of
Business, Distinguished Visiting Fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations,
Academic Board Chairman of the Fung Global Institute in Hong Kong, and Senior
Fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University. His latest book is The Next Convergence – The Future of Economic
Growth in a Multispeed World.
Copyright:
Project Syndicate, 2012.
www.project-syndicate.org
www.project-syndicate.org
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου